🛒Principles of Microeconomics Unit 8 – Perfect Competition
Perfect competition is a market structure where many buyers and sellers trade identical products with no barriers to entry or exit. This model assumes perfect information and price-taking behavior, leading to efficient resource allocation and maximum social welfare.
In perfect competition, firms maximize profits by producing where marginal revenue equals marginal cost. The market reaches equilibrium when supply meets demand, resulting in allocative and productive efficiency. Long-run equilibrium eliminates economic profits as firms freely enter or exit the market.
Perfect competition a market structure characterized by many buyers and sellers, homogeneous products, free entry and exit, and perfect information
Market equilibrium occurs when quantity supplied equals quantity demanded, resulting in a market-clearing price
Profit maximization the primary goal of firms, achieved by producing at the quantity where marginal revenue equals marginal cost (MR=MC)
Economic efficiency achieved when resources are allocated optimally, resulting in the maximum possible social welfare
Allocative efficiency occurs when the price of a good equals its marginal cost of production (P=MC)
Productive efficiency occurs when firms produce at the minimum of their average total cost curve (ATCmin)
Consumer and producer surplus measures of economic welfare that represent the benefits to consumers and producers from participating in a market
Pareto efficiency a state in which no one can be made better off without making someone else worse off
Market Structure Basics
Market structures classified based on the number of firms, product differentiation, barriers to entry and exit, and information availability
Perfect competition, monopolistic competition, oligopoly, and monopoly are the four main market structures
Number of firms in perfect competition, there are many small firms, each with an insignificant market share
Product differentiation in perfect competition, firms sell homogeneous (identical) products
Barriers to entry and exit in perfect competition, there are no barriers, allowing firms to freely enter or exit the market
Information availability in perfect competition, all market participants have perfect information about prices, costs, and product quality
Characteristics of Perfect Competition
Large number of buyers and sellers each individual buyer and seller has no influence on the market price
Homogeneous products all firms sell identical products, making them perfect substitutes for each other
Free entry and exit no barriers prevent new firms from entering the market or existing firms from leaving
Perfect information all market participants have complete knowledge of prices, costs, and product quality
Price-taking behavior firms and consumers are price takers, meaning they accept the market price as given and cannot influence it
No externalities the production or consumption of goods does not result in uncompensated costs or benefits to third parties
No government intervention the market operates without government interference, such as price controls, subsidies, or taxes
Supply and Demand in Perfect Markets
Market supply curve derived by horizontally summing the individual supply curves of all firms in the market
In perfect competition, the market supply curve is the same as the individual firm's supply curve above the shutdown point
Market demand curve represents the total quantity demanded by all consumers at each price level
Equilibrium price and quantity determined by the intersection of the market supply and demand curves
At equilibrium, quantity supplied equals quantity demanded (Qs=Qd)
Changes in supply and demand shifts in the supply or demand curves lead to changes in the equilibrium price and quantity
Factors that shift supply include input prices, technology, expectations, and the number of sellers
Factors that shift demand include income, preferences, prices of related goods, expectations, and the number of buyers
Firm Behavior and Decision Making
Profit maximization firms aim to maximize their profits by choosing the optimal level of output
Profits calculated as total revenue minus total costs (π=TR−TC)
Marginal analysis firms make decisions by comparing marginal revenue (MR) and marginal cost (MC)
Marginal revenue the change in total revenue from selling one additional unit (MR=ΔQΔTR)
Marginal cost the change in total cost from producing one additional unit (MC=ΔQΔTC)
Shutdown point the minimum price at which a firm is willing to continue operating in the short run, equal to the minimum of the average variable cost curve (AVCmin)
Break-even point the price at which a firm's total revenue equals its total costs, equal to the minimum of the average total cost curve (ATCmin)
Long-run decision making in the long run, firms can adjust all inputs and make entry or exit decisions based on economic profits or losses
Short-Run vs. Long-Run Equilibrium
Short run a period in which at least one input is fixed (usually capital), and firms can only adjust variable inputs like labor
In the short run, firms may earn economic profits or losses
Long run a period in which all inputs are variable, and firms can enter or exit the market
In the long run, economic profits and losses are eliminated as firms enter or exit the market
Short-run equilibrium occurs when each firm maximizes its profits by producing at the point where MR=MC
In perfect competition, MR=P, so firms produce where P=MC
Long-run equilibrium occurs when there are no economic profits or losses, and firms produce at the minimum of their long-run average total cost curve (LRATCmin)
In perfect competition, long-run equilibrium implies P=LRATCmin=LMC
Efficiency and Market Outcomes
Allocative efficiency in perfect competition, allocative efficiency is achieved in the long run as price equals marginal cost (P=MC)
This ensures that resources are allocated to their most valued uses
Productive efficiency in perfect competition, productive efficiency is achieved in the long run as firms produce at the minimum of their average total cost curve (ATCmin)
This implies that firms are using the most cost-effective production methods
Consumer and producer surplus in perfect competition, total economic welfare (the sum of consumer and producer surplus) is maximized
Consumer surplus the difference between what consumers are willing to pay and what they actually pay
Producer surplus the difference between what producers receive and their marginal costs
Pareto efficiency perfect competition leads to a Pareto-efficient outcome, as no one can be made better off without making someone else worse off
Real-World Examples and Limitations
Agricultural markets many agricultural markets, such as those for wheat, corn, and soybeans, exhibit characteristics close to perfect competition
Large number of buyers and sellers, homogeneous products, and relatively free entry and exit
Financial markets some financial markets, like foreign exchange markets and stock markets, also resemble perfect competition
Many buyers and sellers, homogeneous assets, and perfect information (in theory)
Limitations of perfect competition model real-world markets often deviate from the strict assumptions of perfect competition
Product differentiation, barriers to entry and exit, imperfect information, and externalities are common in practice
Role of government intervention governments may intervene in markets to address market failures or achieve social objectives
Antitrust laws, regulations, taxes, and subsidies can alter market outcomes and efficiency
Transition to other market structures over time, markets may evolve from perfect competition to other structures like monopolistic competition or oligopoly
Technological changes, economies of scale, and network effects can lead to increased market concentration and product differentiation