💯Math for Non-Math Majors Unit 11 – Voting and Apportionment in Mathematics
Voting systems and apportionment are crucial for fair decision-making in democracies. These mathematical tools determine how individual preferences translate into collective choices and how representatives are allocated among groups based on population size.
Understanding voting methods and apportionment techniques helps us evaluate the fairness of electoral systems. By examining different approaches, we can identify trade-offs between simplicity, representativeness, and resistance to manipulation in democratic processes.
Voting systems determine how individual preferences are aggregated to make collective decisions
Apportionment allocates a fixed number of representatives or resources among competing groups based on their sizes
Fairness criteria establish standards for evaluating the equity and representativeness of voting systems
Plurality voting selects the candidate with the most first-place votes, without requiring a majority
Majority rule requires a candidate to receive more than half of the votes to win
Prevents a candidate disliked by most voters from winning due to vote splitting
Proportional representation aims to allocate seats or influence in proportion to the share of votes received
Quota in apportionment represents the average number of people per representative (total population divided by total representatives)
Divisor methods in apportionment involve dividing each state's population by a common divisor to determine seat allocation
Voting Systems Overview
Voting systems convert individual voter preferences into a collective choice or ranking of candidates
Different voting systems can produce different outcomes for the same set of voter preferences
Some common voting systems include plurality, runoff, instant runoff, approval, score, and Condorcet methods
Arrow's Impossibility Theorem proves no voting system can satisfy a set of reasonable fairness criteria simultaneously
Highlights inherent trade-offs and limitations in designing voting systems
Voting systems must balance competing goals such as simplicity, expressiveness, and resistance to strategic manipulation
The choice of voting system can significantly impact election results and the incentives for candidates and voters
Voting paradoxes, such as Condorcet's paradox and the monotonicity paradox, demonstrate counterintuitive outcomes possible under various systems
Fairness Criteria in Voting
Majority criterion states that if a candidate is preferred by a majority of voters, they should win
Condorcet criterion requires that if a candidate would beat every other candidate in a head-to-head matchup, they should win
Ensures the winner is the candidate who would beat all others in pairwise comparisons
Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives (IIA) means adding or removing a losing candidate should not change the winner
Monotonicity criterion requires that improving the ranking of a winning candidate should not make them lose
Participation criterion encourages voter turnout by ensuring that voting for a preferred candidate never hurts their chances of winning
Consistency criterion states that if an electorate is divided into separate contests, and the same candidate wins each contest, they should win the combined contest
Neutrality means the voting system does not favor any particular candidates or alternatives
Anonymity requires that all voters are treated equally, and swapping any two voters' ballots should not affect the outcome
Common Voting Methods
Plurality voting is simple but vulnerable to vote splitting and the spoiler effect
Runoff voting holds a second round between the top two candidates if no one receives a majority in the first round
Ensures the winner has majority support but may have lower turnout in the second round
Instant runoff voting (IRV) simulates a series of runoffs by eliminating the last-place candidate and redistributing their votes until someone reaches a majority
Allows voters to express preferences without multiple rounds of voting
Approval voting lets voters approve of multiple candidates, and the candidate with the most approvals wins
Encourages voters to support all acceptable candidates rather than just their favorite
Score voting (or range voting) has voters rate each candidate on a scale, and the candidate with the highest average score wins
Provides more nuance than approval voting but may be more complex for voters
Condorcet methods select the candidate who would win a head-to-head matchup against every other candidate
Satisfies the Condorcet criterion but can sometimes result in cyclic preferences with no clear winner
Apportionment Basics
Apportionment is the process of distributing a fixed number of representatives or resources among groups based on their sizes
In the United States, apportionment determines how many seats each state gets in the House of Representatives based on its population
The apportionment problem arises because the ideal quota of representatives per person is usually a fraction, but representatives must be whole numbers
Apportionment methods must decide how to round the ideal quotas to allocate the available seats
The quota is calculated by dividing the total population by the total number of representatives (total population / total representatives)
Represents the average number of people per representative
A state's ideal quota is its population divided by the quota (state population / quota)
The whole number part of the ideal quota is the state's initial allocation of seats
Apportionment methods differ in how they distribute the remaining seats to achieve the total number of representatives required
Apportionment Methods and Paradoxes
Hamilton's method assigns the remaining seats to the states with the largest fractional parts of their ideal quotas
Favors larger states but is susceptible to the Alabama paradox, where a state can lose a seat when the total number of seats increases
Jefferson's method uses a divisor to adjust state populations until the resulting quotients sum to the desired total seats
Favors smaller states and avoids the Alabama paradox but can exhibit the population paradox, where a state with faster population growth loses a seat to a state with slower growth
Webster's method is similar to Jefferson's but rounds the adjusted quotients to the nearest whole number instead of always rounding down
Minimizes the discrepancy between a state's share of seats and its share of the population
The Huntington-Hill method is the current method used for U.S. congressional apportionment and uses a specific geometric mean to determine the priority of states for receiving remaining seats
Balinski and Young's impossibility theorem proves no apportionment method can satisfy a set of desirable properties, including quota (giving each state its ideal quota rounded to the nearest whole number) and monotonicity (a state's number of seats should not decrease when the total number of seats increases)
Real-World Applications
Voting systems are used in political elections, committee decisions, and group choice settings (clubs, awards)
Different voting systems can alter the incentives for candidates, parties, and voters, affecting campaign strategies and voter behavior
Some organizations and jurisdictions have adopted alternative voting systems like instant runoff voting (Australia, Ireland) or approval voting (Fargo, North Dakota) to address limitations of plurality voting
Apportionment methods shape the balance of power in legislative bodies and can have significant impacts on policy outcomes
Changes in apportionment, such as after a census, can shift political representation and advantage or disadvantage certain states or regions
Gerrymandering, the manipulation of electoral district boundaries for partisan advantage, is related to apportionment and can undermine fair representation
Techniques like the efficiency gap measure the extent of gerrymandering
Apportionment principles apply to other problems of proportional allocation, such as distributing resources or benefits among groups (disaster relief funds, university budgets)
Problem-Solving Strategies
Identify the type of problem (voting system analysis, apportionment calculation) and the specific method or criteria involved
For voting system problems, construct a preference schedule showing each voter's ranking of the candidates
Analyze the preference schedule according to the rules of the given voting system
Check for violations of fairness criteria or voting paradoxes
In apportionment problems, calculate the quota (total population / total representatives) and each state's ideal quota (state population / quota)
Apply the specified apportionment method to determine the initial allocation of seats and distribute any remaining seats
Check for apportionment paradoxes by comparing results under different total seat numbers or population distributions
Consider real-world constraints and implications, such as the feasibility of implementing a particular voting system or the political consequences of an apportionment outcome
Use counterexamples to test the limitations of different methods or demonstrate paradoxes
Construct scenarios that highlight the differences between methods or the violation of desired properties
Analyze the sensitivity of results to changes in the inputs, such as voter preferences, candidate fields, or population data
Identify conditions under which the outcome might change or paradoxes might arise
Apply mathematical tools like rounding rules, divisor methods, and pairwise comparisons as appropriate for the specific problem type